The Holocaust (from the Greek ὁλόκαυστος holókaustos: hólos, "whole" and kaustós, "burnt"),[2] also known as The Shoah (Hebrew: השואה, HaShoah, "calamity"; Yiddish: חורבן, Churben or Hurban
Friday, December 21, 2012
IRON MOUNTAIN REPORT
Research Material
REPORT FROM IRON MOUNTAIN ON THE POSSIBILITY
AND DESIRABILITY OF PEACE
WITH INTRODUCTORY MATERIAL BY
LEONARD C. LEWIN
"A BOOK THAT SHOOK THE WHITE HOUSE."
--US. NEWS AND WORLD REPORT
Report from Iron Mountain unveils a hitherto top-secret report of
a government commission that was requested to explore the
consequences of lasting peace on American society. The shocking
results of the study, as revealed in this report, led the government
to conceal the existence of the commission--they had found that,
among other things, peace may never be possible; that even if it
were, it would probably be un-desirable, that "defending the
national interest" is not the real purpose of war; that war is
necessary; that war deaths should be planned and budgeted.
REPORT FROM IRON MOUNTAIN tells the story of how the
project was formed, how it operated, What happened to it. It
includes the complete verbatim text of the commission's hitherto
classified report.
". . . so elaborate and ingenious and so substantively original,
acute, interesting and horrifying, that it will receive serious
attention regardless of its origin."
--The New York Times
"The first major result of the transformation of the war game
into the peace game."
--Irving Louis Horowitz,
Bulletin of the Atomic Scientists
"Should be the occasion for new public demand for a
penetrating examination and evaluation of government reports on
strategic planning for disarmament and peace."
--The Editors of Trans-action
Leonard C. Lewin is a critic and satirist whose work has
appeared in many newspapers and magazines here and abroad.
He is the editor of A Treasury of American Political Humor.
FOREWORD
"John Doe," as I will call him in this book for reasons that will
be made clear, is a professor at a large university in the Middle
West. His field is one of the social sciences, but I will not
identify him beyond this. He telephoned me one evening last
winter, quite unexpectedly; we had not been in touch for several
years. He was in New York for a few days, he said, and there was
something important he wanted to discuss with me. He wouldn't say
what it was. We met for lunch the next day at a midtown
restaurant.
He was obviously disturbed. He made small talk for half an hour,
which was quite out of character, and I didn't press him. Then,
apropos of nothing, he mentioned a dispute between a writer and a
prominent political family that had been in the headlines. What,
he wanted to know, were my views on "freedom of information." How
would I qualify them? And so on. My answers were not memorable,
but they seemed to satisfy him. Then quite abruptly, he began to
tell me the following story:
Early in August of 1963, he said, he found a message on his desk
that a "Mrs. Potts" had called him from Washington. When he
returned the call, a man answered immediately, and told Doe, among
other things, that he had been selected to serve on a commission
"of the high importance." Its objective was to determine,
accurately and realistically, the nature of the problems that
would confront the United States if and when a condition
"permanent peace" should arrive, and to draft a program for
dealing with this contingency. The man described the unique
procedures that were to govern the commission's work and that were
expected to extend its scope far beyond that of any previous
examination of the problems.
Considering that the caller did not precisely identify either
himself or his agency, his persuasiveness must have been of a
truly remarkable order. Doe entertained no serious doubts of the
bona fides of the project, however, chiefly because of his
previous experience with excessive secrecy that often surrounds
quasi-governmental activities. In addition, the man at the other
end of the line demonstrated an impressively complete and
surprisingly detailed knowledge of Doe's word and personal life.
He also mentioned the names of others who were to serve with the
group; most of them were known to Doe by reputation. Doe agreed to
take the assignment --he felt he had no real choice in the matter-
-and to appear the second Saturday following at Iron Mountain, New
York. An airline ticket arrived in his mail the next morning.
The cloak-and-dagger tone of this convocation was further enhanced
by the meeting place itself. Iron Mountain, located near the town
of Hudson, is like something out of Ian Fleming or E. Phillips
Oppenheim. It is an underground nuclear hideout for hundreds of
large American corporations. Most of them use it as am emergency
storage vault for important documents. But a number of them
maintain substitute corporate headquarters as well where essential
personnel could presumably survive and continue to work after an
attack. This latter group included such firms as Standard Oil of
New Jersey, Manufacturers Hanover Trust, and Shell.
I will leave most of the story of the operations of the Special
Study Group, as the commission was formerly called, for Doe to
tell in his own words ("Background Information"). At this point it
is necessary to say only that it met and worked regularly for over
two and a half years, after which it produced a report. It was
this document, and what to do about it, that Doe wanted to talk to
me about.
The Report, he said, had been suppressed--both by the Special
Study Group itself and by the government interagency committee to
which it had been submitted. After months of agonizing, Doe had
decided that he would no longer be party to keeping it secret.
What he wanted from me was advice and assistance in having it
published. He gave me his copy to read, with the express
understanding that if for any reason I were unwilling to become
involved, I would say nothing about it to anyone else.
I read the Report that same night. I will pass over my own
reactions to it, except to say that the unwillingness of Doe's
associates to publicize their findings became readily
understandable. What had happened was that they had been so
tenacious in their determination to deal comprehensively with the
many problems of transition to peace that the original questions
asked of them were never quite answered. Instead, this is what
they concluded:
Lasting peace, while not theoretically impossible, is probably
unattainable; even if it could be achieved it would almost
certainly not be in the best interests of a stable society to
achieve it.
That is the gist of what they say. Behind their qualified academic
language runs this general argument: War fills certain functions
essential to the stability of our society; until other ways of
filling them are developed, the war system must be maintained--and
improved in effectiveness.
It is not surprising that the Group, in its Letter of Transmittal,
did not choose to justify its work to "the lay reader, unexposed
to the exigencies of higher political or military responsibility."
Its Report was addressed, deliberately, to unnamed government
administrators of high rank; it assumed considerable political
sophistication from this select audience. To the general reader,
therefore, the substance of the document may be even more
unsettling than its conclusions. He may not be prepared for some
of its assumptions--for instance, that most medical advances are
viewed more as problems than as progress; or that poverty is
necessary and desirable, public posture by politicians to the
contrary notwithstanding; or that standing armies are, among other
things, social-welfare institutions in exactly the same sense as
are old-people's bones and mental hospitals. It may strike him as
odd to find the probable explanation of "flying saucer" incidents
disposed of en passant in less than a sentence. He may be less
surprised to find that the space program and the controversial
antimissile missile and fallout shelter programs are understood to
have the spending of vast sums of money, not the advancement of
science or national defense, as their principal goals, and to
learn that "military" draft policies are only remotely concerned
with defense.
He may be offended to find the organized repression of minority
groups, and even the re-establishment of slavery, seriously (and
on the whole favorably) discussed as possible aspects of a world
at peace. He is not likely to take kindly to the notion of the
deliberate intensification of air and water pollution (as part of
a program leading to peace), even when the reason for considering
it is made clear. That a world without war will have to turn
sooner rather than later to universal test-tube procreation will
be less disturbing, if no more appealing. But few readers will
not be taken aback, at least, by a few lines in the Report's
conclusions, repeated in its for recommendations, that suggest
that the long-range planning--and "budgeting"--of the "optimum"
number lives to be destroyed annually in overt warfare is high on
the Group's list of priorities for government action.
I cite these few examples primarily to warn the general reader
what he can expect. The statesmen and strategists for whose eyes
the Report was intended obviously need no such protective
admonition.
This book of course, is evidence of my response to Doe's request.
After carefully considering the problems that might confront the
publisher of the Report, we took it to The Dial Press. There, its
significance was immediately recognized, and, more important, we
were given firm assurances that no outside pressures of any sort
would be permitted to interfere with its publication.
It should be made clear that Doe does not disagree with the
substance of the Report, which represents a genuine consensus in
all important respects. He constituted a minority of one--but only
on the issue of disclosing it to the general public. A look at how
the Group dealt with this question will be illuminating.
The debate took place at the Group's last full meeting before the
Report was written, late in March, 1966, and again at Iron
Mountain. Two facts must be kept in mind, by way of background.
The first is that the Special Study Croup had never been
explicitly charged with or sworn to secrecy, either when it was
convened or at any time thereafter. The second is that the Group
had nevertheless operated as if it had been. This was assumed from
the circumstances of its inception and from the tone of its
instructions. (The Group's acknowledgment of help from "the many
persons . . . who contributed so greatly to our work" is somewhat
equivocal; these persons were not told the nature of the project
for which their special resources of information were solicited. )
Those who argued the case for keeping the Report secret were
admittedly motivated by fear of the explosive political effects
that could be expected from publicity. For evidence, they pointed
to the suppression of the far less controversial report of then-
Senator Hubert Humphrey's subcommittee on disarmament in l962.
(Subcommittee members had reportedly feared that it might be used
by Communist propagandists, as Senator Stuart Symington put it, to
"back up the Marxian theory that war production was the reason for
the success of capitalism.") Similar political precautions had
been taken with the better-known Gaither Report in 1957, and even
with the so-called Moynihan Report in 1965.
Furthermore, they insisted, a distinction must be made between
serious studies, which are normally classified unless and until
policy makers decide to release them, and conventional "showcase"
projects, organized to demonstrate a political leadership's
concern about an issue and to deflect the energy of those pressing
for action on it. (The example used, because some of the Croup had
participated in it, was a "White House Conference" on
international cooperation, disarmament, etc., which had been
staged late in 1965 to offset complaints about escalation of the
Vietnam war.)
Doe acknowledges this distinction, as well as the strong
possibility of public misunderstanding. But he feels that if the
sponsoring agency had wanted to mandate secrecy it could have done
so at the outset. It could also have assigned the project to one
of the government's established "think tanks," which normally work
on a classified basis. He scoffed at fear of public reaction,
which could have no lasting effect on long-range measures that
might be taken to implement the Group's proposals, and derided the
Group's abdication of responsibility for its opinions and
conclusions. So far as he was concerned, there was such a thing as
a public right to know what was being done on its behalf; the
burden of proof was on those who would abridge it.
If my account seems to give Doe the better of the argument,
despite his failure to convince his colleagues, so be it. My
participation in this book testifies that I am not neutral. In my
opinion, the decision of the Special Study Group to censor its own
findings was not merely timid but presumptuous. But the refusal,
as of this writing, of the agencies for which the Report was
prepared to release it themselves raises broader questions of
public policy. Such questions center on the continuing use of
self-serving definitions of "security" to avoid possible political
embarrassment. It is ironic how often this practice backfires.
I should state, for the record, that I do not share the attitudes
toward war and peace, life and death, and survival of the species
manifested in the Report. Few readers will. In human terms, it is
an outrageous document. But it does represent a serious and
challenging effort to define an enormous problem. And it explains,
or certainly appears to explain, aspects of American policy
otherwise incomprehensible by the ordinary standards of common
sense. What we may think of these explanations is something else,
but it seems to me that we are entitled to know not only what they
are but whose they are.
By "whose" I don't mean merely the names of the authors of the
Report. Much more important, we have a right to know to what
extent their assumptions of social necessity are shared by the
decision-makers in our government. Which do they accept and which
do they reject. However disturbing the answers, only full and
frank discussion offers any conceivable hope of solving the
problems raised by the Special Study Croup in their Report from
Iron Mountain.
L.C.L.
New York, June 1967
BACKGROUND INFORMATION
[The following account of the workings of the Special Study Group
is taken verbatim from a series of tape-recorded interviews I had
with "John Doe." The transcript has been edited to minimize the
intrusion of my questions and comments, as well as for length, and
the sequence has been revised in the interest of continuity.
L.C.L]
How was the Group formed?
.,, The general idea for it, for this kind of study, dates back at
least to l96l. It started with some of the new people who came in
with the Kennedy administration, mostly, I think, with McNamara,
Bundy, and Rusk. They were impatient about many things.... One of
them was that no really serious work had been done about planning
for peace--a long-range peace, that is, with long-
range planning.
Everything that had been written on the subject [before l96l] was
superficial. There was insufficient appreciation of the scope of
the problem. The main reason for this, of course, was that the
idea a of a real peace in the world, general disarmament and so
on, was looked on as utopian. Or even crackpot. This is still
true, and it's easy enough to understand when you look at what's
going on in the world today.... It was reflected in the studies
that had been made up to that time. They were not realistic.. . .
The idea of the Special Study, the exact form it would take, was
worked out early in '63.... The settlement of the Cuban missile
affair had something to do with it, but what helped most to get it
moving were the big changes in military spending that were being
planned.... Plants being closed, relocations, and so forth. Most
of it wasn't made public until much later....
[I understand] it took a long time to select the people for the
Group. The calls didn't go out until the summer....
Who made the selection?
That's something I can't tell you. I wasn't involved with the
preliminary planning. The first I knew of it was when I was called
myself. But three of the people had been in on it, and what the
rest of us know we learned from them, about what went on earlier.
I do know that it started very informally. I don't know what
particular government agency approved' the project.
Would you care to make a guess?
All right--I think it was an ad hoc committee, at the cabinet
level, or near it. It had to be. I suppose they gave the
organizational job--making arrangements, paying the bills, and so
on--to somebody from State or Defense or the National Security
Council. Only one of us was in touch with Washington, and I wasn't
the one. But I can tell you that very, very few people knew about
us. ., . For instance, there was the Ackley Committee. It was set
up after we were. If you read their report-- the same old tune--
economic re conversion, turning sword plants into plowshare
factories--I think you'll wonder if even the President knew about
our Group. The Ackley Committee certainly didn't.
Is that possible, really?
I mean that not even the President knew of your commission?
Well, I don't think there's anything odd about the government
attacking a problem at two different levels.
Or even about two or three government agencies working at cross-
purposes. It happens all the time. Perhaps the President did know.
And I don't mean to denigrate the Ackley Committee1, but it was
exactly that narrowness of approach that we were supposed to get
away from. . You have to remember--
you've read the Report-- that what they wanted from us was a
different kind thinking. It was a matter of approach. Herman Kal
calls it "Byzantine"--no agonizing over cultural and I religious
values. No moral posturing. It's the kind of thinking that Rand
and the Hudson Institute and I.D.A.2 brought into war
planning.... What they asked us to do, and I think; we did it, was
to give the same kink of treatment to the hypothetical problems
of peace as they give to a hypothetical nuclear war....We may have
gone further than they expected, but once you establish your
premises and your logic you can't turn back....
Kahn's books3, for example, are misunderstood, at least by laymen.
They shock people. But you see, what's important about them is not
his conclusions, or his opinions. It's the method. He has done
more than anyone else I can think of to get the general public
accustomed to the style of modern military thinking....Today it's
possible for a columnist to write about "counter force strategy"
and "minimum deterrence" and "credible first-strike capability"
without having to explain every other word. He can write about war
and strategy without getting bogged down in questions of
morality....
The other big difference about our work is breadth. The Report
speaks for itself. I can't say that we took every relevant aspect
of life and society into account, but I don't think we missed
anything essential . . .
Why was the project given to an outside commission?
Why couldn't it have been handled directly by an appropriate
government agency?
I think that's obvious, or should be. The kind of thinking wanted
from our Group just isn't to be had in a formal government
operation. Too many constraints. Too many inhibitions. This isn't
a new problem. Why else would outfits like Rand and Ingersol stay
in business? Any assignment that's at all sophisticated is almost
always given to an outside group. This is true even in the State
Department, in the "gray" operations, those that arc supposed to
be unofficial, but are really as official as can be. Also with the
C.l.A....
For our study, even the private research centers were too
institutional.... A lot of thought went into making sure that our
thinking would be unrestricted. All kinds of little things. The
way we were called into the Group, the places we met, all kinds of
subtle devices to remind us. For instance, even our name, the
Special Study Group. You know government names. Wouldn't you think
we'd have been called "Operation Olive Branch," or "Project
Pacifica," or something like that? Nothing like that for us--too
allusive, too suggestive. And no minutes of our--meetings--too
inhibiting.... About who might be reading them. Of course, we took
notes for our own use. And among ourselves, we usually called
ourselves "The Iron Mountain Boys' or "Our Thing," or whatever
came to mind....
What can you tell me about the members of the Group ?
I'll have to stick to generalities.... There were fifteen of us.
The important thing was that we represented a very wide range of
disciplines. And not all academic. People from the natural
sciences, the social sciences, even the humanities. We had a
lawyer and a businessman. Also, a professional war planner. Also,
you should know that everyone in the Group had done work of
distinction in at least two different fields. The
interdisciplinary element was built in....
It's true that there were no women in the Group, but I don't think
that was significant.... We were all American citizens, of course.
And all, I can say, in very good health, at least when we
began.... You see, the first order of business, at the first
meeting, was the reading of dossiers. They were very detailed, and
not just professional, but also personal. They included medical
histories. I remember one very curious thing, for whatever it's
worth. Most of us, and that includes me, had a record of
abnormally high uric acid concentrations in the blood... None of
us had ever had this experience, of a public inspection of
credentials, or medical reports. It was very disturbing....
But it was deliberate. The reason for it was to emphasize that we
were supposed to make all our own decisions on procedure, without
outside rules. This include judging each others qualifications and
making allowances for possible bias. I don't think it affected
our work directly, but it made the point it was supposed to
make...That we should ignore absolutely nothing that might
conceivably affect our objectivity.
[At this point I persuaded Doe that a brief occupational
description of the individual members of the Group would serve a
useful purpose for readers of the Report. The list which follows
was worked out on paper. (It might be more accurate to say it was
negotiated.) The problem was to give as much relevant information
as possible without violating Doe's commitment to protect his
colleagues' anonymity. It turned out to be very difficult,
especially in the cases of those members who are very well known.
For this reason, secondary areas of achievement or reputation are
usually not shown,
The simple alphabetical "names" were assigned by Doe for
convenient reference; they bear no intended relation to actual
names. "Able" was the Camp's Washington contact. It was he who
brought and read the dossiers, and who most often acted as
chairman. He, "Baker" and "Cox" were the three who had been
involved in the preliminary planning There is no other
significance to the order of listing.
"Arthus Able" is an historian and political theorist, who has
served in government.
"Bernard Baker" is a professor of international law and a
consultant on government operations.
"Charles Cox" is an economist, social critic; and biographer.
"John Doe."
"Edward Ellis" is a sociologist often involved in public affairs.
"Frank Fox" is a cultural anthropologist
"George Green" is a psychologist, educator, and developer of
personnel testing systems.
"Harold Hill" is a psychiatrist, the has conducted extensive
studies of the relationship between individual and group behavior.
"John Jones is a scholar and literary critic.
'Martin Miller" is a physical chemist, whose work has received
international recognition at the highest level.
"Paul Peters" is a biochemist, who has made important discoveries
bearing on reproductive processes.
"Richard Roe" is a mathematician affiliated with
an independent West Coast research institution.
"Samuel Smith" is an astronomer, physicist, and communications
theorist.
"Thomas Taylor" is a systems analyst and war planner, who has
written extensively on war, peace, and international relations.
"William White" is an industrialist, who has under-taken many
special government assignments.]
How did the Group operate? I mean, where and when did you meet,
and so forth?
We met on the average of once a month. Usually was on weekends,
and usually for two days. We had few longer sessions, and one that
lasted only four hours . . . We met all over the country, always
at a different place, except for the first and last times, which
were a Iron Mountain. It was like a traveling seminar....
Sometimes at hotels, sometimes at universities. Twice we met at
summer camps, and once at a private estate, in Virginia. We used a
business place in Pittsburgh, and another in Poughkeepsie [New
York].... We never met in Washington, or on government property
anywhere....Able would announce the times and places two meetings
ahead. They were never changed....
We didn't divide into subcommittees, or anything else that formal.
But we all took individual assignments between meetings. A lot of
it involved getting information from other people.... Among the
fifteen of us, I don-t think there was anybody in the academic or
professional world we couldn't call on if we wanted to, and we
took advantage of it.... We were paid a very modest per diem. All
of it was called "expenses" on the vouchers. We were told not to
report it on our tax returns.... The checks were drawn on a
special account of Able's at a New York bank. He signed them.... I
don't know what the study cost. So far as our time and travel were
concerned, it couldn't have come to more than the low tax-figure
range. But the big item must have been computer time, and I have
no idea how high this ran....
You say that you don't think your work was affected by
professional bias. What about political and philosophical bias? Is
it possible to deal with questions of war and peace without
reflecting personal values?
Yes, it is. I can understand your skepticism. But if you had been
at any of our meetings you'd have had a very hard time figuring
out who were the liberals and who were the conservatives, or who
were hawks and who were doves. There is such a thing as
objectivity, and I think we had it.... I don't say no one had any
emotional
reaction to what we were doing. We all did, to some extent. As a
matter of fact, two members had heart attacks after we were
finished, and I'll be the first to admit it probably wasn't a
coincidence.
You said you made your own ground rules. What were these ground
rules?
The most important were informality and unanimity. By informality
I mean that our discussions were open ended. We went as far afield
as any one of us thought we had to. For instance, we spent a lot
of time on the relationship between military recruitment policies
and industrial employment. Before we were finished with it, we'd
one through the history of western penal codes and any number of
comparative psychiatric studies [of draftees and volunteers]. We
looked over the organization of the Inca empire. We determined the
effects of automation on underdeveloped societies.... It was all
relevant...
By unanimity, I don't mean that we kept taking votes; like a jury.
I mean that we stayed with every issue until we had what the
Quakers call a "sense of the meeting " It was time-consuming. But
in the long run it saved time. Eventually we all got on the same
wavelength, so to speak....
Of course we had differences, and big ones especially in the
beginning.... For instance, in Section 1 you might think we were
merely clarifying our instructions. Not so; it took a long time
before we all agreed to a strict interpretation....Roe and Taylor
deserve most of the credit for this.... There are many things in
the Report that look obvious now, but didn't seem so obvious then.
For instance, on the relationship of war to social systems. The
original premise was conventional, from Clausewitz. . . That war
was an "instrument" of broader political values. Able was the only
one who challenged this, at first. Fox called his position
"perverse." Yet it was Fox who furnished most of the data that led
us all to agree with Able eventually. I mention this because I
think it's good example of the way we worked. A triumph of method
over cliché.... I certainly don't intend to go into details about
who took what side about what, and when. But I will say, to give
credit where due, that only Roe, Able, Hill, and Taylor were able
to see, at the beginning, where our method was taking us.
But you always reached agreement, eventually.
Yes. It's a unanimous report.... I don't mean that our sessions
were always harmonious. Some of them were rough. The last six
months there was a lot of quibbling about small points.... We'd
been under pressure for a long time, we'd been working together
too long. It was natural . . . that we got on each other's nerves.
For a while Able and Taylor weren't speaking to each other. Miller
threatened to quit. But this all passed. There were no important
differences....
How was the Report actually written? Who did the writing?
We all had a hand in the first draft. Jones and Able put it
together, and then mailed it around for review before working out
a final version.... The only problems were the form it should take
and whom we were writing it for. And, of course, the question of
disclosure....[Doe's comments on this point are summarized in the
introduction.]
You mentioned a "peace games" manual. What are peace games?
I wanted to say something about that. The Report barely mentions
it. "Peace games' is a method we developed during the course of
the study. It's a forecast technique, an information system. I'm
very excited about it. Even if nothing is done about our
recommendations--which is conceivable--this is something that
can't be ignored. It will revolutionize the study social problems.
It's a by-product of the study. We needed a fast, dependable
procedure to approximate the effects of disparate social phenomena
on other social phenomena. We got it. It's in a primitive phase,
but works.
How are peace games played? Are they like Rand's war games?
You don't "play" peace games, like chess or Monopoly any more than
you play war games with toy soldiers. You use computers. Its a
programming system. A compute "language," like FORTRAN, or ALGOL,
or Jovial.... Its advantage is its superior capacity to
interrelate data with no apparent common points of reference.... A
simple analogy is likely to be misleading. But I can give you some
examples. For instance, supposing I asked you to figure out what
effect a moon landing by U.S. astronauts would have on an election
in, say, Sweden. Or what effect a change in the draft law--a
specific change-- I'd have on the value of real estate in downtown
Manhattan? Or a certain change in college entrance requirements
in the United States on the British shipping industry?
You would probably say, first, that there would be no effect to
speak of, and second, that there would be no way of telling. But
you'd be wrong on both counts. In each case there would be an
effect, and the peace games method could tell you what it would
be, quantitatively. I didn't take these examples out of the air.
We used them working out the method.... Essentially, it's an
elaborate, high-speed trial-and-error system for determining
working algorithms. Like most sophisticated types of computer
problem-solving....
A lot of the "games" of this kind you read about are just
glorified conversational exercises. They really are games, and
nothing more. I just saw one reported in the Canadian Computer
Society Bulletin, called a "Vietnam Peace Game." They use
simulation techniques, but the programming hypotheses are
speculative....
The idea of a problem-solving system like this is not original
with us. ARPA4 has been working on something like it. So has
General Electric, in California. There are others.... We were
successful not because we know more than they do about
programming, which we don't but because we learned how to
formulate the problem accurately. It goes back to the old saw. You
can find the answer if you know the right question....
Supposing you hadn't developed this method. Would you have come
to the same conclusions in the Report?
Certainly. But it would have taken many times longer.... But
please don't misunderstand my enthusiasm [about the peace games
method]. With all due respect to the effects of computer
technology on modern thinking, basic judgments must still be made
by human beings. The peace games technique isn't responsible for
our Report. We are....
1. This was a "Committee on the Economic Impact of Defense and
Disarmament," headed by Gardner Ackley, of the Council of Economic
Advisers. It was established by Presidential order in December,
1963, and issued a report in July, 1965.
2. The Institute for Defense Analysis
3. On Thermonuclear War, Thinking About the Unthinkable, On
Escalation
4. The Advanced Research Projects Agency, of the Department of
Defense.
STATEMENT BY "JOHN DOE"
CONTRARY to the decision of the Special Study Croup, of which I
was a member, I have arranged for the general release of our
Report. I am grateful to Mr. Leonard C. Lewin for his invaluable
assistance in making this possible, and to The Dial Press for
accepting the challenge of publication. Responsibility for taking
this step, however is mine and mine alone.
I am well aware that my action may be taken as a breach of faith
by some of my former colleagues. But my view my responsibility to
the society of which am a part supersedes any self-assumed
obligation on the part of fifteen individual men. Since our Report
can be considered on its merits, it is not necessary for me to
disclose their identity to accomplish my purpose. Yet I would
gladly abandon my own anonymity if it were possible to do so
without at the same time compromising theirs, to defend our work
publicly if and when they release me from this personal bond.
But this is secondary. What is needed now, and needed badly, is
widespread public discussion and debate about the elements of war
and the problems of peace. I hope that publication of this Report
will serve to initiate it.
THE REPORT OF THE SPECIAL STUDY GROUP
***************************************************************
LETTER OF TRANSMITTAL
***************************************************************
TO THE CONVENER OF THIS GROUP:
Attached is the Report of the Special Study Group established by
you in August, 1963, 1) to consider the problems involved in the
contingency of a transition to a general condition of peace, and
2) to recommend procedures for dealing with this contingency. For
the convenience of non technical readers we have elected to submit
our statistical supporting data, totaling 604 exhibits,
separately, as well as a preliminary manual of the "peace games"
method devised during the course of our study.
We have completed our assignment to the best of our ability,
subject to the limitations of time and resources available to us.
Our conclusions of fact and our recommendations are unanimous;
those of us who differ in certain secondary respects from the
findings set forth herein do not consider these differences
sufficient to warrant the filing of a minority report. It is our
earnest hope that the fruits of our deliberations will be of value
to our government in its efforts to provide leadership to the
nation in solving the complex and far-reaching problems we have
examined, and that our recommendations for subsequent
Presidential action in this area will be adopted.
Because of the unusual circumstances surrounding the establishment
of this Group, and in view of the nature of its findings, we do
not recommend that this Report be released for publication. It is
our affirmative judgment that such action would not be in the
public interest. The uncertain advantages of public discussion of
our conclusions and recommendations are, in our opinion, greatly
outweighed by the clear and predictable danger of a crisis in
public confidence which untimely publication of this Report might
be expected to provoke. The likelihood that a lay reader,
unexposed to the exigencies of higher political or military
responsibility, will misconstrue the purpose of this project, and
the intent of its participants, seems obvious. We urge that
circulation of this Report be closely restricted to those whose
responsibilities require that they be apprised of its contents.
We deeply regret that the necessity of anonymity, a prerequisite
to our Group's unhindered pursuit of its objectives, precludes
proper acknowledgment of our gratitude to the many persons in and
out of government who contributed so greatly to our work.
For the Special Study Group
[signature withheld for publication]
30 September, 1966
INTRODUCTION
THE REPORT which follows summarizes the results of a two-and--
half-year study of the broad problems to be anticipated in the
event of a general transformation of American society to a
condition lacking its most critical current characteristics: its
capability and readiness to make war when doing so is judged
necessary or desirable by its political leadership.
Our work has been predicated on the belief that some kind of
general peace may soon be negotiable. The de facto admission of
Communist China into the United Nations now appears to be only a
few years away at most. It has become increasingly manifest that
conflicts of American national interest with those of China and
the Soviet Union are susceptible of political solution, despite
the superficial contraindications of the current Vietnam war, of
the threats of an attack on China, and of the necessarily hostile
tenor of day-to-day foreign policy statements. It is also obvious
differences involving other nations can be readily resolved by the
three great powers whenever they arrive at a stable peace among
themselves. It is not necessary, for the purposes of our study, to
assume that a general détente of this sort will come about--and we
make no such argument--but only that it may.
It is surely no exaggeration to say that a condition of general
world peace would lead to changes in the social structures of the
nations of the world of unparalleled and revolutionary magnitude.
The economic impact of general disarmament, to name only the most
obvious consequence of peace, would revise the production and
distribution patterns of the globe to a degree that would make the
changes of the past fifty years seem insignificant. Political,
sociological, cultural, and ecological changes would be equally
far-reaching. What has motivated our study of these contingencies
has been the growing sense of thoughtful men in and out of
government that the world is totally unprepared to meet the
demands of such a situation.
We had originally planned, when our study was initiated, to
address ourselves to these two broad questions and their
components: What can be expected of peace comes? What should me be
prepared to do about it? But as our investigation proceeded it
became apparent that certain other questions had to be faced.
What, for instance, are the real functions of war in modern
societies, beyond the ostensible ones of defending and advancing
the "national interests" of nations? In the absence of war, what
other institutions exist or might be devised to fulfill these
functions? Granting that a "peaceful" settlement of disputes is
within the range of current international relationships, is the
abolition of war, in the broad sense, really possible? If so, is
it necessarily desirable, in terms of social stability? If not,
what can be done to improve the operation of our social system in
respect to its war-readiness?
The word peace, as we have used it in the following pages,
describes a permanent, or quasi-permanent, condition entirely free
from the national exercise, or contemplation, of any form of the
organized social violence, or threat of violence, generally known
as war. It implies total and general disarmament. It is not used
to describe the more familiar condition of "cold war," "armed
peace," or other mere respite, long or short, from armed conflict.
Nor is it used simply as a synonym for the political settlement of
international differences. The magnitude of modern means of mass
destruction and the speed of modern communications require the
unqualified working definition given above; only a generation ago
such an absolute description would have seemed utopian rather than
pragmatic. Today, any modification of this definition would render
it almost worthless for our purpose. By the same standard, we have
used the word war to apply interchangeably to conventional ("hot")
war, to the general condition of war preparation or war readiness,
and to the general "war system." The sense intended is made clear
in context.
The first section of our Report deals with its scope and with the
assumptions on which our study was based. The second considers the
effects of disarmament on economy, the subject of most peace
research to date. The third takes up so-called "disarmament
scenarios" which have been proposed. The fourth, fifth, and sixth
examine the nonmilitary functions of war and the problems they
raise for a viable transition to peace; here will be found some
indications of the true dimensions of the problem not previously
coordinated in any other study. In the seventh section we
summarize our findings, and in the eighth we set forth our
recommendations for what I believe to be a practical and necessary
course of action.
SECTION 1
SCOPE OF THE STUDY
WHEN THE SPECIAL STUDY GROUP was established in August, l963, its
members were instructed to govern their deliberations in
accordance with three principal criteria. Briefly stated, they
were these: 1) military-style objectivity; 2) avoidance of
preconceived value assumptions; 3) inclusion of all relevant areas
of theory and data.
These guideposts are by no means as obvious as they may appear at
first glance, and we believe it necessary to indicate clearly how
they were to inform our work. For they express succinctly the
limitations of previous "peace studies," and imply the nature of
both government and official dissatisfaction with these earlier
efforts. It is not our intention here to minimize the significance
of the work of our predecessors, or to belittle the quality of
their contributions. What we have tried to do, and believe we have
done, is extend their scope. We hope that our conclusions may
serve in turn as a starting point for still broader and more
detailed examinations of every aspect of the problems of
transition to peace and of the questions which must be answered
before such a transition can be allowed to get under way.
It is a truism that objectivity is more often an intention
expressed than an attitude achieved, but the intention--conscious,
unambiguous, and constantly self-critical --is a precondition to
its achievement. We believe it no accident that we were charged to
use a "military contingency" model for our study, and we owe a
considerable debt to the civilian war planning agencies for their
pioneering work in the objective examination of the contingencies
of nuclear war. There is no such precedent in peace studies. Much
of the usefulness of even the most elaborate and carefully
reasoned programs for economic conversion to peace, for example,
has been vitiated by a wishful eagerness to demonstrate that peace
is not only possible, but even cheap or easy. One official report
is replete with references to the critical role of "dynamic
optimism" on economic developments, and goes on to submit, as
evidence, that it "would be hard to imagine that the American
people would not respond very positively to an agreed and
safeguarded program to substitute an international rule of law and
order," etc.1 Another line of argument frequently taken is that
disarmament would entail comparatively little disruption of the
economy, since it need only be partial; we will deal with this
approach later. Yet genuine objectivity in war studies is often
criticized as inhuman. As Herman Kahn, the writer on strategic
studies best known to the general public, put it: "Critics
frequently object to the icy rationality of the Hudson Institute,
the Rand Corporation, and other such organizations. I'm always
tempted to ask in reply, 'Would you prefer a warm, human error? Do
you feel better with a nice emotional mistake?"2 And as Secretary
of Defense Robert S. McNamara has pointed out, in reference to
facing up to the possibility of nuclear war, "Some people are
afraid even to look over the edge. But in a thermonuclear war we
cannot afford any political acrophobia."3 Surely it should be
self-evident that this applies equally to the opposite prospect,
but so far no one has taken more than a timid glance over the
brink of peace.
An intention to avoid preconceived value judgments is if anything
even more productive of self-delusion. We claim no immunity, as
individuals, from this type of bias, but we have made a
continuously self-conscious effort to deal with the problems of
peace without, for example, considering that a condition of peace
is per se "good" or "bad." This has not been easy, but it has been
obligatory; to our knowledge, it has not been done before.
Previous studies have taken the desirability of peace, the
importance of human life, the superiority of democratic
institutions, the greatest "good" for the greatest number, the
"dignity" of the individual, the desirability of maximum health
and longevity, and other such wishful premises as axiomatic values
necessary for the justification of a study of peace issues. We
have not found them so. We have attempted to apply the standards
of physical science to our thinking, the principal characteristic
of which is not quantification, as is so popularly believed, but
that, in Whitehead's words, "...it ignores all judgment value; for
instance, all esthetic and moral judgments."4 Yet it is obvious
that any serious investigation of a problem, however "pure," must
be informed by some normal positive standard. In this case it has
been simply the sum of human society in general, of American
society in particular, and, as a corollary to survival, the
stability of society.
It is interesting, we believe, to note that the most passionate
planners of nuclear strategy also recognize that the stability of
society is the one bedrock value that cannot be avoided. Secretary
McNamara has defended the need for American nuclear superiority on
the grounds that it "makes possible a strategy designed to press
the fabric of our societies if war should occur."5 A former
member of the Department of State policy planning staff goes
further. "A more precise word for peace, in terms of the practical
world, is stability.... Today the great nuclear panoplies are
essential elements in such stability exists. Our present purpose
must be to continue I process of learning how to live with them."6
We, of course do not equate stability with peace, but we accept it
as the one common assumed objective of both peace and war.
The third criterion--breadth--has taken us still farther afield
from peace studies made to date. It is obvious to any layman
that the economic patterns of a warless world will be drastically
different from those we live wish today, and it is equally obvious
that the political relationships of nations will not be those we
have learned to take for granted, sometimes described as a global
version of the adversary system of our common law. But the social
implications of peace extend far beyond its putative effects on
national economies and international relations. As we shall show,
the relevance of peace and war to the internal political
organization of societies, to the sociological relationships of
their members, to psychological motivations, to ecological
processes, and to cultural values is equally profound. More
important, it is equally critical in assaying the consequences of
a transition to peace, and in determining the feasibility of any
transition at all.
It is not surprising that these less obvious factors have been
generally ignored in peace research. They have not lent themselves
to systematic analysis. They have been difficult, perhaps
impossible, to measure with any degree of assurance that estimates
of their effects could be depended on. They are "intangibles," but
only in the sense that abstract concepts in mathematics are
intangible compared to those which can be quantified. Economic
actors, on the other hand, can be measured, at least
superficially; and international relationships can be verbalized,
like law, into logical sequences.
We do not claim that we have discovered an infallible way of
measuring these other factors, or of assigning them precise
weights in the equation of transition. But we believe we have
taken their relative importance into account to this extent: we
have removed them from the category of the "intangible," hence
scientifically suspect and therefore somehow of secondary
importance, and brought them out into the realm of the objective.
The result, we believe, provides a context of realism for the
discussion of the issues relating to the possible transition to
peace which up to now has been missing.
This is not to say that we presume to have found the answers we
were seeking. But we believe that our emphasis on breadth of scope
has made it at least possible to begin to understand the
questions.
SECTION 2
DISARMAMENT AND THE ECONOMY
IN THIS SECTION we shall briefly examine some of the common
features of the studies that have been published dealing with one
or another aspect of the expected impact of disarmament on the
American economy. Whether disarmament is considered as a by-
product of peace or as its precondition, its effect on the
national economy will in either case be the most immediately felt
of its consequences. The quasi-mensurable quality of economic
manifestations has given rise to more detailed speculation in this
area than in any other.
General agreement prevails in respect to the more important
economic problems that general disarmament would raise. A short
survey of these problems, rather than a detailed critique of their
comparative significance, is sufficient for our purposes in this
Report.
The first factor is that of size. The "world war industry," as one
writer' has aptly called it, accounts for approximately a tenth of
the output of the world's total economy. Although this figure is
subject to fluctuation, e causes of which are themselves subject
to regional variation, it tends to hold fairly steady. The United
States as the world's richest nation, not only accounts for the
largest single share of this expense, currently upward of $60
billion a year, but also ". . . has devoted a higher proportion
[emphasis added] of its gross national product A its military
establishment than any other major free world nation. This was
true even before our increased expenditures in Southeast Asia."
Plans for economic con-version that minimize the economic
magnitude of the problem do so only by rationalizing, however
persuasively, the maintenance of a substantial residual military
budget under some euphemized classification.
Conversion of military expenditures to other purposes entails a
number of difficulties. The most serious stems from the degree of
rigid specialization that characterizes modern war production,
best exemplified in nuclear and missile technology. This
constituted no fundamental problem after World War 11, nor did the
question of free-market consumer demand for "conventional" items
of consumption--those goods and services consumers had already
been conditioned to require. Today's situation is qualitatively
different in both respects.
This inflexibility is geographical and occupational, as well as
industrial, a fact which has led most analysts of economic impact
of disarmament to focus their attention on phased plans for the
relocation of war industry personnel and capital installations as
much as on proposals for developing new patterns of consumption.
One serious flaw common to such plans is the kind called in the
natural sciences the "macroscopic error." An implicit presumption
is made that a total national plan for conversion differs from a
community program to cope with the shutting down of a "defense
facility" only in degree. We find no reason to believe that this
is the case, nor that a general enlargement of such local
programs, however well thought out in terms of housing,
occupational retraining, and the like, can be applied on a
national scale. A national economy can absorb almost any number of
subsidiary reorganizations within its total limits, providing
there is no basic change in its own structure. General
disarmament, which would require such basic changes, lends itself
to no valid smaller-scale analogy.
Even more questionable are the models proposed for time retraining
of labor for non armaments occupations. Putting aside for the
moment the unsolved questions dealing with the nature of new
distribution patterns-- retraining for what?--the increasingly
specialized job skills associated with war industry production are
further depreciated by the accelerating inroads of the industrial
techniques loosely described as "automation." It is not too much
to say that general disarmament would require the scrapping of a
critical proportion of the most highly developed occupational
specialties in the economy. The political difficulties inherent in
such an "adjustment would make the outcries resulting from the
closing of few obsolete military and naval installations in 1964
sound like a whisper.
In general, discussions of the problems of conversion have been
characterized by an unwillingness to recognize its special
quality. This is best exemplified by the 1965 report of the
Ackley Committee. One critic has tellingly pointed out that it
blindly assumes that " ....nothing in the arms economy--
neither its size, nor its geographical concentration, nor its
highly specialized nature, nor the peculiarities of its market,
nor the special nature of much of its labor force--endows it with
any uniqueness when the necessary time of adjustment comes."'
Let us assume, however, despite the lack of evidence that a viable
program for conversion can be developed in the framework of the
existing economy, that the problems noted above can be solved.
What proposals have been offered for utilizing the productive
capabilities that disarmament would presumably release?
The most commonly held theory is simply that general economic
reinvestment would absorb the greater part of these capabilities.
Even though it is now largely taken for granted (and even by
today's equivalent of traditional laissez-faire economists) that
unprecedented government assistance (and concomitant government
control) will be needed to solve the "structural" problem of
transition, a general attitude of confidence prevail that new
consumption patterns will take up the slack What is less clear is
the nature of these patterns.
One school of economists has it that these patterns will develop
on their own. It envisages the equivalent the arms budget being
returned, under careful control, to the consumer, in the form of
tax cuts. Another, recognizing the undeniable need for increased
"consumption in what is generally considered the public sector of
the economy, stresses vastly increased government spending in such
areas of national concern as health, education, mass
transportation, low-
cost housing, water supply, control of the physical environment,
and, stated generally poverty."
The mechanisms proposed for controlling the transition to an arms-
free economy are also traditional-changes in both sides of the
federal budget, manipulation of interest rates, etc. We
acknowledge the undeniable value of fiscal tools in a normal
cyclical economy, when they provide leverage to accelerate or
brake an existing trend. Their more committed proponents, however,
tend to lose sight of the fact that there is a limit to the power
of these devices to influence fundamental economic forces. They
can provide new incentives in the economy, but they cannot in
themselves transform the production of a billion dollars' worth of
missiles a year to the equivalent in food, clothing, prefabricated
houses, or television sets. At bottom, they reflect the economy;
they do not motivate it.
More sophisticated, and less sanguine, analysts COD-template the
diversion of the arms budget to a non military system equally
remote from the market economy, What the "pyramid-builders"
frequently suggest is the expansion of space-research programs to
the dollar level of current armaments expenditures. This approach
has the superficial merit of reducing the size of the problem of
transferability of resources, but introduces other difficulties,
which we will take up in section 6.
Without singling out any one of the several major studies of the
expected impact of disarmament on the economy for special
criticism, we can summarize our objections to them in general
terms as follows:
1. No proposed program for economic conversion to disarmament
sufficiently takes into account the unique magnitude of the
required adjustments it would entail.
2. Proposals to transform arms production into a beneficent scheme
of public works are more the product of wishful thinking than of
realistic understanding of the limits of our existing economic
system.
3. Fiscal and monetary measures are inadequate as controls for the
process of transition to an arms-free economy,
4. Insufficient attention has been paid to the political
acceptability of the objectives of the proposed conversion models,
as well as of the political means to be employed in effectuating a
transition.
S. No serious consideration has been given, in any proposed
conversion plan, to the fundamental nonmilitary function of war
and armaments in modern society, nor has any explicit attempt been
made to devise a viable substitute for it. This criticism will be
developed in sections 5 and 6.
SECTION 3
DISARMAMENT SCENARIOS
SCENARIOS, as they have come to be called, are hypothetical
constructions of future events. Inevitably, they re composed of
varying proportions of established fact, reasonable inference, and
more or less inspired guess-work. Those which have been suggested
as model procedures for effectuating international arms control
and eventual disarmament are necessarily imaginative, al-though
closely reasoned; in this respect they resemble the "war games"
analyses of the Rand Corporation, with which they share a common
conceptual origin.
All such scenarios that have been seriously put forth imply a
dependence on bilateral or multilateral agreement between the
great powers. In general, they call for a progressive phasing out
of gross armaments, military forces, weapons, and weapons
technology, coordinated with elaborate matching procedures of
verification, inspection, and machinery for the settlement of
international disputes. It should be noted that even proponents of
unilateral disarmament qualify their proposals with an implied
requirement of reciprocity, very much in the manner of a scenario
of graduated response in nuclear war. The advantage of unilateral
initiative lies in its political value as an expression of good
faith, as well as in its diplomatic function as a catalyst for
formal disarmament negotiations.
The READ model for disarmament (developed by the Research Program
on Economic Adjustments to Disarmament) is typical of these
scenarios. It is a twelve-year-program, divided into three-year
stages. Each stage includes a separate phase of: reduction of
armed forces; cutbacks of weapons production, inventories, and
foreign military bases; development of international inspection
procedures and control conventions; and the building up of a
sovereign international disarmament organization. It anticipates a
net matching decline in U.S. defense expenditures of only somewhat
more than half the 1965 level, but a necessary re deployment of
some five-sixths of the defense-dependent labor force.
The economic implications assigned by their authors to various
disarmament scenarios diverge widely, The more conservative
models, like that cited above, emphasize economic as well as
military prudence in postulating elaborate fail-safe disarmament
agencies, which themselves require expenditures substantially
substituting for those of the displaced war industries. Such
programs stress the advantages of the smaller economic adjustment
entailed Others emphasize, on the contrary, the magnitude (and the
opposite advantages) of the savings to be achieved from
disarmament. One widely read analysis' estimates the annual cost
of the inspection function of general disarmament throughout the
world as only between two and three percent of current military
expenditures. Both types of plan tend to deal with the anticipated
problem of economic reinvestment only in the aggregate. We have
seen no proposed disarmament sequence that correlates the phasing
out of specific kinds of military spending with specific new forms
of substitute spending.
Without examining disarmament scenarios in greater detail, we may
characterize them with these general comments:
1. Given genuine agreement of intent among the great powers, the
scheduling of arms control and elimination presents no inherently
insurmountable procedural problems. Any of several proposed
sequences might serve as the basis for multilateral agreement or
for the first step in unilateral arms reduction.
2. No major power can proceed with such a program, however, until
it has developed an economic conversion plan fully integrated with
each phase of disarmament. No such plan has yet been developed in
the United States.
3. Furthermore, disarmament scenarios, like proposals for economic
conversion, make no allowance for the non-military functions of
war in modern societies, and offer no surrogate for these
necessary functions. One partial exception is a proposal for the
"unarmed forces of the United States," which we will consider in
section 6.
Go To Part 2
Go To Part 3
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment